亚洲免费av电影一区二区三区,日韩爱爱视频,51精品视频一区二区三区,91视频爱爱,日韩欧美在线播放视频,中文字幕少妇AV,亚洲电影中文字幕,久久久久亚洲av成人网址,久久综合视频网站,国产在线不卡免费播放

        ?

        Using RCEP: Creating Products for Asia

        2020-03-30 03:27:50Elms
        中國-東盟博覽(政經(jīng)版) 2020年3期

        Elms

        Now that the 15 Asian countries in the Regional Comprehensive Economic Partnership (RCEP) trade agreement have concluded negotiations, attention is turning to how companies might actually use the deal. While all the specifics will not be known until texts and schedules are released at signature in February or March, one important concept is worth exploring in greater detail: how this agreement has the potential to radically transform trade with just one element — a regional rule of origin.

        To appreciate why this single item is so important, it worth stepping back to understand in a simplified way how companies make goods without any trade deals and how they struggle to manage production across multiple trade agreements.

        Take the example of a bottle of shampoo (HS3305). This is a useful example for many reasons. First, both large and small companies compete to sell shampoo to customers. Second, this is an item that has universal appeal, where local or regional variations are likely to be relatively modest. Third, shampoo can have a lot of ingredients which are rarely found in just one country. Finally, it tends to be subject to an interesting variation in protection at the domestic level in Asia. Perhaps surprisingly, shampoo often faces relatively high tariff barriers at the border. Applied MFN tariffs (those actually charged on imported goods) can be 10%-20% into many markets in Asia.

        Without any trade agreement in place, a company that wants to send shampoo into a new foreign market will need to create the product and pay the Most Favored Nation (MFN) tariff rate for shampoo.

        Depending on the market, some shampoo firms may have access to lower tariffs by using free trade agreements (FTAs). These FTA agreements are typically designed to give preferences or benefits to member country firms that non-member firms do not receive. This usually includes at least lower tariffs, or even zero tariffs (duty-free access), on most or all products between member countries.

        The size and scope of these preferences depends on the negotiations. Higher quality agreements, in general, give deeper tariff cuts on a bigger set of goods. The best FTAs aim for duty-free treatment on all goods.

        For firms, however, these benefits can come with a catch. Lower tariffs do not come automatically. Companies have to demonstrate that they qualify for preferences. Typically, products need to be either 100% “from” the member countries in the agreement (grown, harvested, or dug up as an example) or show that the product has been “substantially transformed” in the member countries to qualify.

        If the item is 100% “from” the members of the FTA, this seems straightforward. Most people intuitively grasp that a carrot or potato traded between two parties in an FTA should qualify for lower tariffs in a bilateral trade deal.

        Shampoo, of course, is not grown or harvested. Ingredients are probably sourced from outside one market and may include items from outside both (or all) of the parties in the FTA. How much of the total content in the bottle of shampoo needs to be “from” the members to count for lower tariffs?

        Trade negotiators spend a lot of time negotiating the rules of origin to account for these problems. While not getting into the technical details here, basically the members often agree on a threshold that has to be satisfied to allow a product to “count” so the product qualifies for lower tariffs under the trade agreement.

        A bottle of shampoo may have 20 ingredients on the label. Depending on the rules, in an agreement with just two members, it can be tricky for some countries to create a bottle of shampoo with enough content from just the two members to ever meet the thresholds to qualify for origin and get the benefits of the lower tariffs on offer. Smaller economies, especially, struggle to find enough domestic resources to satisfy content for products, as so many raw materials, parts and components are imported.

        This is partly why firms do not often use FTAs, even if they might appear to benefit from the agreement. If firms find the FTA rules too bothersome, if the tariff preferences are small compared to MFN rates, or if products simply dont qualify, companies can always ship products under the MFN tariff levels and avoid using an FTA at all.

        For many companies that have the ability to use different FTAs, the world is both full of benefits and more complicated.

        Take the example of a small firm in Singapore trying to make shampoo for shipment across Asia. Singapore currently has more than 20 different FTAs in place that each provide special preferences, including potential for shampoo tariff reductions.

        However, the rules of origin are going to be a problem. The Singaporean firm relies on imported materials to create the final product. Even if the Singaporean company gets many items from within ASEAN and has a huge potential advantage with using six existing ASEAN trade agreements, it could still struggle to ship across Asia. Depending on where it sources all the other materials from, it may or may not qualify for lower tariffs into different markets.

        To illustrate the problem, if the firm wanted to send a bottle to South Korea, it may need to ensure that it adds more Korean ingredients to meet rules of origin under ASEAN/Korea.

        If the company got an order from Japan, it may not be able to use the same bottle, because the Korean “content” would not count. It may need to be swapped out for Japanese raw materials instead to qualify for lower tariffs under ASEAN/Japan.

        If a staff member in Singapore accidently shipped the Japanese content bottle to Korea and claimed FTA preferences under ASEAN/Korea, the firm could be liable for mis-declaration with potentially significant fees and penalties.

        Under RCEP, however, the shampoo company can make shampoo safe in the knowledge that — as long as the content in the bottle comes from anywhere in the 15 markets in Asia meeting the ROOs for RCEP — it can be shipped to any of the 15 markets in Asia without any changes in formulation. Given the size and diversity of these markets, this is a significant advantage to all Asia-based firms.

        Even better, under RCEP, firms will need to fill out only one sheet of paper to prove that their products “qualify” for origin. The new RCEP certificate of origin (CO) should reduce costs and time for companies.

        The extent of the benefits, ie, the lower tariffs on offer, will vary in RCEP. In some instances, the gap between the MFN rate or existing FTA benefits and new RCEP rates may be small. But the ability to ship products, like shampoo, across all of Asia without change in formulation, is still extremely significant. It means that firms will be competitive in markets that they may never have considered in the past.

        This apparently small element of RCEP is likely to be game changing. Companies should start preparing now to use this trade agreement.

        · Source: Asian Trade Center

        多毛小伙内射老太婆| 特级毛片全部免费播放a一级| 国产免费视频一区二区| 国产亚洲成人精品久久久| 欧美大片aaaaa免费观看| 亚洲aⅴ无码成人网站国产app | 亚洲色四在线视频观看| 亚洲精品综合中文字幕组合 | 午夜精品久久久久久久无码| 欧美成a人片在线观看久| 精品无码成人片一区二区| 精品熟女av中文字幕| 夜夜夜夜曰天天天天拍国产| 亚洲熟女综合一区二区三区| 无码一区东京热| 亚洲av极品尤物不卡在线观看 | 午夜性无码专区| 亚洲国产福利精品一区二区| 国产精品久久国产精品久久| 日本一级特黄aa大片| 黑人巨大跨种族video| 无码片久久久天堂中文字幕| 中文字幕一区二区在线看| 色综合天天综合欧美综合 | 午夜国产小视频在线观看黄| 成人性生交大片免费入口| 一个人看的视频www免费| 妺妺窝人体色www在线直播| 国产午夜视频高清在线观看| 日韩大片高清播放器大全| 韩国精品一区二区三区无码视频 | 中文字幕av无码免费一区| 亚洲av高清在线观看三区| 日韩一二三四区在线观看| 特黄熟妇丰满人妻无码| 中文字幕+乱码+中文字幕无忧| 久久精品国产亚洲av热一区| 日韩少妇人妻中文视频| 50岁熟妇大白屁股真爽| 欧美色图50p| av在线播放中文专区|